Economists in the US are overwhelmingly in favor of free
trade. But they continue to be frustrated that the public doesn’t buy their
arguments. So frustrated are they that last May, one of the leading
pro-free-trade think tanks, the Peterson Institute, invited highly respected
economist Alan Blinder, now a Princeton professor and formerly Federal Reserve
Vice Chairman to give a talk on why the public doesn’t buy the free trade
gospel.
Professor Blinder titled his talk at Peterson Why, After 200 Years, Can’t Economists Sell
Free Trade? It’s an accurate
title. Blinder cited public opinion polls showing Americans highly skeptical of
trade. One poll showed the public felt by a 48%-29% margin that trade with
other countries leads to job losses at home rather than job gains. Another poll
showed the public favored renegotiating trade agreements by a huge 64%-28%
margin. It’s clear that polls can vary
widely: polls using language about jobs tend to get strong anti-free trade results
while polls that ask for opinions on low priced imports will get a positive
response to free trade. Blinder argued, like many pro-free trade economists,
that the American public just doesn’t understand or appreciate the benefits of
free trade, in particular the benefit of lower prices to consumers.
But there is another explanation for public opinion. It may
not be that the public is too dumb or emotional to comprehend free trade—it may
be that the public senses that free trade does not deliver long-term economic
growth. And in that view the public would be right. It was conspicuous that in
his Peterson talk, Blinder did not once mention long-term economic growth.
Americans care of course about low prices. But in the bigger political and
social picture, they care more about what they can expect for their jobs and
their standard of living over the five or ten years to come. They also care
about the prospects for their children. And those issues are linked to the rate
of growth, not price levels. And the fact is that the economics of
international trade has little to nothing to say about long-term economic
growth.
Noneconomists are often surprised by that statement. They
imagine that economic theory embraces all economic forces, and so when
economists argue that free trade is positive for the US economy, they mean it’s
positive in the short and long term and for all major economic variables
including the growth rate. But international trade economics is a division of
microeconomics (the economics of prices and markets). It has nothing at all to
say at the theoretical level about how free trade contributes to growth. It may
be that low prices created by free trade contribute to economic growth by
making goods cheap and enabling people to create new businesses. On the other
hand, it may be that high prices and prosperity lead to growth by giving
potential customers and investors more money in their pockets to fund new
businesses. .
Perhaps the best example illustrating the disconnect between
free trade and growth comes from David Ricardo, the British economist who first
explained the theory of comparative advantage underlying free trade 200 years
ago. Ricardo explained that whereas in the early 19th century,
Britain and Portugal each produced wool and wine, both economies could make
themselves instantly better off by trading and specializing—Britain in wool and
Portugal in wine, because the differing climates guaranteed higher productivity
of wool in Britain and wine in Portugal. This analysis was precisely right, and
Britain’s influence over the weak Portuguese monarchy enabled it to be largely
fulfilled. But from a long-term growth perspective, this specialization was a
boon for Britain and disastrous for Portugal. Britain specialized in one of the
global boom industries of the 19th century, textiles and apparel,
while Portugal chose to specialize in an industry where profit margins were
small and growth prospects dim, partly because other nearby countries produced
far more wine from much better soil. Today, 200 years later, Portugal is still wrestling
with the inheritance of this awful choice (exacerbated by a euro regime which
enforces deflation on the country). Portugal would have done better 200 years
ago to have rejected free trade and pursued a protectionist policy to build up
its domestic industries partially sheltered from British competition (as France
and the German states chose to do).
As far as I have been able to discover, there is only one
economics textbook focused on the relationship between trade and growth, International Trade and Economic Growth, by
Hendrik van den Berg and Joshua Lewer, published in 2007. Van den Berg and Lewer point out as I have
explained that there is no universal theoretical connection between free trade
(or protectionism) and economic growth. They also point out that in the long
term, growth is far more important than low prices. “Estimates of the static gains from trade are very small, on the order
of 1 to 2 percent of GDP. Such small gains suggest that free trade is just not
very important…The largest gains from trade are the long-term dynamic gains derived
from international trade’s positive effect on economic growth.” (Van den
Berg and Lewer, pg. 250) This is a point that has, in a roundabout way, been
endorsed by Paul Krugman, our foremost trade economist, who has said that “In
the long-run, productivity is not quite everything, but almost everything.”
Krugman was referring to labor productivity growth, a measure of long-term
economic growth per employee and closely linked to the aggregate rate of
long-term growth. Note that what Krugman did not say is that in the long-term (or the short-term), low
prices are everything.
The importance of growth can be illustrated by a simple
mathematical exercise. Economists at the IMF and elsewhere generally agree that
the US dollar is overvalued. An overvalued dollar helps to keep prices down but
it also restrains economic growth by making US goods less competitive at home
against imports and in foreign markets too. With colleagues at the Coalition
for a Prosperous America, I’ve published a paper
showing that the US dollar’s overvaluation can be estimated at about 25% today.
Whenever we talk about reducing the dollar’s value, somebody is sure to protest
that prices of imported goods will increase. But the benefits to growth, in
terms of increased exports and reduced imports, that would flow from giving our
exporters and domestic competitors a (huge) 25% boost in competitiveness are
rarely considered. In Figure 1 we show the effects of dollar devaluation on both prices and economic growth. Case 1
shows the US economy chugging along at a stable 1.75% growth rate, more or less
the growth rate we’ve seen recently. In Case 2, we look at the effects of a
dollar devaluation that leads to faster growth. We assume that in 2018, we
drive the value of the dollar down by 25%. Since imports account for about 15%
of our economy, this would deliver a 4% increase in prices across the entire
economy, so inflation reduces the real value of GDP to just 96 in 2019. But
devaluation also adds 1 percentage point to the growth rate. This boost to the
growth rate is very powerful: by 2025, seven years after the start of this
policy, we’ve caught up to Case 1; by ten years out, Case 2 is 3% ahead; and 20
years out, Case 2 is 14% ahead. That’s a huge benefit in terms of standard of
living, overwhelming the higher prices of imports through economic growth.
Figure 1: Dollar
Devaluation Generates Faster Economic Growth
In their book, van den Berg and Lewer examine the many
statistical studies on the relationship between growth and the two categories
they call “open economies” and “closed economies.” There is clearly a
correlation between faster economic growth and more openness over the last 40
years, although they point out the relationship is heavily influenced by the
four economies known as the East Asian tigers (Hong Kong, Singapore, South
Korea, Taiwan). In my view, it is
misleading to lump these four economies together with other so-called “open” (i.e.
free trade) economies. A new category is needed for the tigers, and other
similar economies, because they are not “open” in the same way that Britain or
the US is open. Those four countries practice something better called “managed
trade.” Managed trade economies focus on running a trade surplus as a path to
growth. Singapore, which has the best growth record of pretty much any
diversified economy in the world, has run a current account surplus (current
account is a broader measure including the trade balance and a few other items)
every year since 1988. In those 28 years, Singapore’s current account as a
percent of its GDP has never fallen below the high level of 6.9% and last year
came in at 19%, one of the highest levels in the world. Other countries that
have chosen to run consistently large current account surpluses and delivered
high long-term growth include Germany and China.
Van den Berg and Lewer divide economists’ theories of growth
into two groups. One, associated with economist Robert Solow, attributes growth
to technological innovation, and sees it as mostly random, i.e. driven by
unpredictable scientific discoveries or inventions. Economist Robert Gordon
follows the Solow school of thought and his recent book, The Rise and Fall of American Growth, argues that
Growth economist Robert Solow |
The second major group of growth theories could be called
Schumpeterian. They derive from the work of Austrian-American economist Joseph
Schumpeter. These theories also see technology as the most important driving
force in long-term economic growth. But they argue that growth rates can be
raised by the right forms of corporate organization and by a process Schumpeter
christened “creative destruction.” Schumpeterian
growth theories look at issues like the level of research spending in the
economy, and the freedom for new competitors to challenge existing players.
The important point to note is that neither of these growth
theories include any systematic link to
Economist Joseph Schumpeter (1883-1950) |
The theory of comparative advantage and free trade are among
the “crown jewels” of academic economics, to quote Harvard Professor Dani
Rodrik. It suits academic economists (and their colleagues in many Washington
think tanks) to argue that free trade is a great policy and superior to a
closed economy. In my view, this binary choice is an obsolete discussion and a
hangover from the mid-20th century. Economic developments since the
watershed year of 1973 (when the US enacted a 90-day import tariff and stopped
the free exchange of gold for dollars) have shown that we are in a different,
more complex world. The US economy is incapable of balancing its trade—in other
words we can only pay for all we import with loans from foreigners—and one day
those loans will stop coming. The rise of Asian economies shows that managed
trade as a strategy works.
But managed trade on its own is not enough. The most
successful managed trade nations are the ones that target and favor the
industries they view as offering high and rising productivity rates. In
general, those are manufacturing industries. Free trade, as practiced in the
Anglo-Saxon nations that are its greatest enthusiasts, is leading to an
ever-greater shift from high-productivity manufacturing to low-productivity
service industries. The small nations that practice managed trade, like
Singapore and Hong Kong, have already surpassed most of the free trade
enthusiasts in living standards per person. The larger managed trade nations,
like South Korea and Germany, are on the way to doing so. It’s time for the US
to wake up to the realities of trade and growth in the modern world.
No comments:
Post a Comment