Bretton Woods Hotel, site of 1944 monetary conference |
As President Trump moves to implement economic policies aimed at
increasing U.S.-based production, incomes, and jobs, there’s a growing risk
that the dollar will become further overpriced. The dollar is already way too high, as
evidenced by our 41 consecutive years of trade deficit.
Further dollar appreciation would make the
job of growing the U.S. economy harder. It would probably diminish some of the
potential gains the Trump Administration is trying to achieve in trade policy.
Reducing and ideally eliminating our trade deficit, is important. The bloated
dollar valuation, and dollar volatility, makes that harder.
The belief that the dollar will rise as U.S. economic expansion
takes hold over the course of the next year or two is gaining currency amongst
economists and financial market participants. It’s based partly on the view
that the Federal Reserve will raise interest rates as growth rises; it’s also
based on the experience of the early 1980s when President Reagan’s economic
expansion, combined with Paul Volcker’s sharp hike in interest rates, drove the
dollar up. On top of those possible effects, there are also some commentators
like the New York Times’ Paul Krugman and Professor Barry Eichengreen arguing
that any efforts to improve the trade deficit are self-defeating, partly, one
suspects, because they hold the global monetary system (or what’s left of it)
dear, and they don’t want to see the Trump Administration walking away from the
U.S.’s role as leader, occasional enforcer, and perennial savior of that
limping system. Even financially astute commentators, like Mohammed El-Erian,
former fund manager at Pimco and Harvard Management, agree that the dollar is
likely to rise. Writing in the Financial Times, El-Erian recently wrote: “If
the new administration ends up alone in pursuing pro-growth policies, the
dollar would appreciate further because of two powerful divergent forces: the
relative economic outperformance of the U.S. that entices more direct foreign
investment; and a tighter Federal Reserve policy stance that attracts larger
inflows of financial capital.”
So what to do? There are several policy options that should be
considered to counteract any significant rise in the dollar. We will look at three in this article.
[Note: a shorter version of this article is available at the CPA site here.]
[Note: a shorter version of this article is available at the CPA site here.]
The first way to counteract unwelcome dollar strength could be an
effort to charge other countries as currency manipulators and use focused U.S.
leverage, such as trade sanctions, to get them to allow their currencies to
appreciate. Recently, Senate Minority Leader Charles Schumer (D-NY) urged the
president to label China a currency manipulator. The “currency manipulator”
label, under current law, simply triggers dialogue with the offending country.
That dialogue could lead to further action at the discretion of the
President. The problem with this
approach is that the persistent Chinese currency manipulation problem has ebbed
for the moment. Indeed, the table below from the U.S. Treasury’s October 2016
monitoring report on foreign currency shows that China actually spent a huge $566
billion trying to boost
the renminbi against other currencies, including the dollar.
It’s nevertheless clear that China is using multiple techniques
to boost its exports and restrain imports. They include state subsidies to many
of its largest companies; requiring joint ventures and technology transfer for
foreign companies entering China, and making it hard for foreign companies to
sell inside China, to name just a few. But when it comes to currency
manipulation, which China practiced on a gargantuan scale between 2000 and 2014
(during which time it accumulated as much as $4 trillion of dollar-denominated
assets), it may not be happening now. So the U.S. Treasury would be like the
well-intentioned police officer who stormed into the house of the neighborhood’s
most notorious married couple, only to find that the bullying husband hasn’t
been abusing his spouse this week.
Under a 1988 law, the Treasury currently uses three indicators
for each trading partner: a bilateral goods deficit of over $20 billion (in the
trailing four quarters), a current account deficit of more than 3%, and
persistent purchases of foreign currency (to hold down their own
currency). These are all valid and
revealing indicators—China ran a $356 billion bilateral surplus with the U.S.,
prima facie evidence of its addiction to export-led growth; Germany runs the
world’s highest current account surplus, at 9.1% of GDP, also a reliable
indicator of a strategy of export-led growth with restrained domestic
consumption. Finally, Taiwan and Switzerland intervene to hold down their
currencies. But, as can be seen in the
table, none of our major trading partners went into the “red” on all three
indicators as of last October.
Source: U.S. Treasury, Foreign Exchange Policies of Major Trading Partners of the U.S., Oct. 2016. Pg. 35. |
Consumers of Last Resort
For an economist, currency “manipulation” is better understood not as a result of direct
intervention to manipulate an exchange rate, but as a set of policies that
prevent a nation’s trade balance from balancing over a full economic cycle
(typically 5-7 years). Also last
October, economist Brad Setser of the Council on Foreign Relations published a
paper, The
Return of the East Asian Savings Glut, that should be required reading
for every policymaker in Washington. Setser explained that the driver for trade
surpluses in East Asia and Germany is a commitment to export-led growth and
very high domestic savings rates in those countries, which in turn forces other
countries to run deficits, with consequences including manufacturing decline,
deficient total demand and a tendency towards asset bubbles. Variations on this
argument have also been made by CPA Advisory Board member Dan Alpert in his
book The
Age of Oversupply and by former Treasury Secretary Larry Summers
in his articles
on secular
stagnation. But Setser updates the discussion, pointing out that East
Asian savings have now recovered from their temporary decline in the recession,
to reach $7 trillion, equivalent to a stunning 10% of world GDP. Astronomic savings rates of about 40% of
annual GDP (China’s savings rate reached 48% in 2015) result from very high
trade surpluses—worth 4% of GDP for East Asia. The situation in Europe has
worsened as the deficit nations have cut back on their deficits following the
wave of Euro-crises, while surplus nations have not cut back on surpluses. The
result is that a handful of nations, led by the U.S. but also including the
U.K., Australia, Canada, and Turkey, are forced to run deficits, and see their
productive capacity hollowed out. “The problem of the global savings glut is
now more acute than in 2005,” Setser writes. “The social costs—and therefore
also political costs—of relying on the United States and a few other countries
as consumers of last resort are increasingly evident.”
Withholding Tax
Setser favors international pressure on East Asian nations to
reduce their savings rates. But there are also unilateral policies that can act
directly on the U.S. exchange rate to reduce our deficit. Joe Gagnon and Gary
Hufbauer of Washington’s Peterson Institute proposed in a 2011 article, Taxing
China’s Assets,
a novel idea for taxing certain foreign nations’ holding of U.S. financial
assets. The core of the proposal was a 30% withholding tax on the interest paid
on holdings of foreign entities based in nations that the U.S. deemed
persistent surplus nations. Gagnon suggests the criteria could be similar to
the second Treasury criteria: a persistent current account surplus across a
full business cycle. China and Germany would qualify right out of the gate. The
benefits of the proposal are that it not only would exert downward pressure on
the dollar (and upward pressure on the renminbi) and provide a disincentive for
Chinese public or private entities to invest in U.S. dollar assets, but that it
would also make it plain to the Chinese and other surplus nations that they are
not doing the U.S. a favor by buying our Treasury bonds or other assets. On the
contrary, they are enabling their economies to grow at our expense, and we
would much prefer they increase domestic consumption rather than rely upon US
consumers for growth. Rather than
advancing this remedy through international institutions which include the
mercantilist members benefiting from their strategy, the U.S. could simply
enact this policy and levy a tax. As an illustration, Gagnon and Hufbauer
speculated in 2011 that this policy could drive the renminbi up by some 20%,
cutting our current account by as much as $125 billion and boosting the economy
by 750,000 new jobs.
Gagnon identified two potential challenges for the implementation
of a withholding tax, legislation and enforcement. Legally, the withholding tax may require
Congressional modification to tax treaties the U.S. has with China and many
other nations. Given the current mood in Congress, and what could be an
emerging bipartisan consensus on the need to take action on trade (not just
Schumer but Democratic Senator Sherrod Brown of Ohio has also recently spoken
approvingly of the president’s aggressive approach on trade), such legislative
changes could be achievable. But singling out individual nations is always
politically contentious. The enforcement issue is more complex. Enforcing a
significant withholding rate on selected nations and nationals creates an
incentive to disguise the buyers and holders of assets. The international banking system has proven its
ability to report relatively reliably on assets and flows, but such a system
could still be costly. For that reason, Gagnon is now intrigued by a third,
even more radical approach to reducing the U.S. current account deficit: a
market access charge or MAC.
Market Access Charge
The MAC is the brainchild of economist John Hansen, now retired after a career
at the World Bank. Hansen’s vision, contained in his paper International
Trade and Manufacturing Policies for the 21st Century, is
for a charge, starting at 50 basis points (half of 1%) on all inflows of
foreign capital into U.S. financial assets. The one-time charge upon entry would
be levied not on the interest but on the principal invested into U.S. assets.
Thus there is no judgment required on which nation may be violating various
criteria. And the revenue flowing to the Treasury would be counted in billions
of dollars. The MAC is simply a response to a world in which the U.S. deficit
is too large, has continued for too long, and the costs are too great for the
U.S. economy. By discouraging the overseas purchase of U.S. assets, it will
also make it harder for the U.S. government to run deficits, or at least tend
towards higher interest rates if it does so, a good thing for many reasons.
“The MAC would be collected automatically and electronically by the computer
systems of the six or seven U.S. gateway banks that handle most of America’s
cross-border financial transactions,” Hansen writes. “Funds in this account
could be used only for improving the global competitiveness of American
enterprises and workers, or for reducing the burden of U.S. Government debt
held by foreign countries.”
“This is a no-fail policy,” Joe Gagnon told this author. “Either it pushes down the dollar which boosts exports, or even if it had no effect, it would generate a ton of money for the Treasury.” He adds however that the U.S. should open discussions on currency with surplus nations before moving to enact a MAC.
“This is a no-fail policy,” Joe Gagnon told this author. “Either it pushes down the dollar which boosts exports, or even if it had no effect, it would generate a ton of money for the Treasury.” He adds however that the U.S. should open discussions on currency with surplus nations before moving to enact a MAC.
The advantages of the MAC are that it is relatively easy to
administer and it is highly likely to drive down the dollar, boosting the U.S
economy.
One potential risk is that this policy could signal to the world
that the U.S. no longer wishes the dollar to be the sole widely held
international reserve and transaction currency. According to the Bank for
International Settlements 88% of currency transactions involve the U.S. dollar.
However, as Hansen points out, governments are already moving away from
over-reliance on the dollar. Between 2000 and 2013, according to IMF data, the
dollar fell from 72 percent of allocated international reserves to only 61
percent There is a risk we might push
the dollar down more aggressively than expected. Financial markets sometimes
overreact to new developments. Thus, implementation of a MAC should be
accompanied by complete transparency of U.S. intentions. This would be an important step towards a
multi-currency world, while large losses for those nations that have purchased
U.S. assets to maintain their beggar-thy-neighbor high savings rate would be a
pleasant consolation for Americans.
The MAC addresses the fundamental distortion that emerged in
1944-1946 when the present so-called Bretton Woods foreign exchange system was
established. Back then, the U.S. as the leading surplus nation, rejected John
Maynard Keynes’ proposals to require both surplus and deficit nations to
address imbalances. Keynes foresaw that if only deficit nations were required
to address imbalances, the system would have a deflationary bias. Today, the
U.S., now the world’s leading deficit nation, is stuck with a problem of its
own creation. The MAC solution, discouraging excessive speculative or mercantilist
purchases of the dollar, is an ingenious one because it sidesteps a thousand
political arguments over cause and responsibility. By impacting the dollar
directly, the policy will exert a powerful impact across the entire “real” and
financial economy. It will also tell our partners that we are serious about
modifying a system based on a unipolar post-World War II world, and making it
work for today’s multipolar world.
No comments:
Post a Comment