Towards a Post-Globalization
World
Britain, Brexit, and a New
Economic Direction
In a recent New York Times article,
a reporter visited Wigan in the north of England to try to understand why
Britain voted to leave the European Union. He spoke to a 61-year-old pro-Brexit
voter, a worker at a canned food factory named Colin whose weekly income had
fallen by 52% in the last three years, from $665 (£443)
to $318 (£212). For Colin, that was painful.
Still worse, he told the newspaper, was that the factory had moved from
standard full-time contracts to “zero hour” contracts where the company decides
each day how many hours Colin is needed. “It is basically slave labor,” Colin
told the Times. This decline in wages and labor relations for semi-skilled and
unskilled workers is partly due to increased competition from eastern European
workers. The reporter interviewed a Pakistani and a Polish immigrant in Wigan,
each of whom expressed strong views in favor of restricting immigration to
benefit current residents’ access to jobs and social services. Another
interesting report, a video
in the Guardian made the same case, interviewing voters in seven different
cities who attributed economic and social service problems to immigrants from
eastern Europe. Another powerful story
in the (London) Times visited the former coalmining village of Grimethorpe in
Yorkshire to find voters angry about the local warehouse firm recruiting
unskilled labor in Poland to work in Grimethorpe while turning down local
residents who applied for jobs. One woman said that on polling day, she went
around the village urging at least 50 friends and family to remember to vote
and vote “Out”. These are not
“irrational” voters as London commentators, who lately like to call themselves
the “cosmopolitan elite” suggest. Voters are acutely rational and aware when it
comes to effects on their own livelihoods.
A small but growing number of economists are coming to
realize that globalization is itself the key part of the problem causing
economic stagnation in certain nations.
While globalization can in very broad terms be described as a process
that makes the world economy more efficient by shifting production to low-cost
nations, it’s by no means clear that such efficiency leads to higher growth
rates for all nations. In fact, looking at Figure 1, you
can see that growth rates in the 21st century are lower than they
were in the 1990-2000 period for every major nation in the table, with the
exception of Switzerland. (The World Bank data is based on GDP per person
adjusted for purchasing power parity, so as to make international comparisons
fair.) Globalization as implemented since 2000 is highly advantageous to those
economies that were properly prepared to exploit the opportunity, but highly
disadvantageous to those economies that were not prepared, for two reasons: The
high-wage losers face growing competition from low-wage competitors, and their
economies were oriented towards meeting domestic demand rather than
international demand. Those losers have become the turkeys at the globalization
Christmas dinner. Three major economies fit that description well: the U.S.,
the U.K., and France. To put it another
way: you don’t join the Premier League without a strategy. Or: those who fail
to plan are planning to fail.
Figure 1 shows that the U.S. lost 1.3 percentage points of
annual growth in the 21st century as compared to the 1990-2000
period. In the U.K. the loss was 1 point and in France 1.2 points. Bearing in
mind the power of compound growth, these are significant and substantial losses
in national income that add up over time. They impact those in the lower
portions of the income distribution far more than those in the upper. The
critical challenge for those three economies is to restore growth to 20th
century levels. I believe that’s achievable. One has simply to learn from the
countries that have benefited from globalization.
Figure 1: Major Economy Growth Before & After Globalization Acceleration |
World-Class and
World-Scale Industries
In a globalized world, industries tend to concentrate in
fewer countries with larger production facilities. We have seen this trend in automobiles
for some 40 years. After its success in autos, Japan went on to achieve a large
position in semiconductor manufacture. As a result, semiconductor production in
the U.S. began to decline. (The present writer worked for the only U.S. company
to build a new greenfield semiconductor fabrication facility in Silicon Valley
in the 21st century, Infinera Corporation.) Globalization truly took
off around the year 2000 in the wake of two developments: China’s accession to
the World Trade Organization, and the series of events from the Maastricht
Treaty of 1992, to the entry of low-income eastern European economies into the
EU, and finally the creation of the Eurozone in 1999. Even though it did not
join the euro, Britain was impacted by EU developments, through the free
movement of EU citizens and from investment strategies based on a general
belief that the European economy was headed for much tighter integration than
ever before.
The result was an unprecedented migration of production, and
lately services, to larger facilities in fewer countries. The smartphone is
often described as the defining consumer product of the 21st century.
In general, the smartphone in your pocket consists of chips built in Japan,
Korea, and Taiwan, assembled onto a circuit card in China, and covered with a
layer of hardened glass made in China. It may be true that the software running
the smartphone was written in Cupertino, California, and one key chip was
designed in Cambridge, England, but those functions involve far, far fewer jobs
than the production jobs in Asia. Another example: the Internet is a defining
institution of the 21st century. Half a century ago, we all had to
make do with telephones. In Britain, those phones were manufactured in Britain
and communicated over a network of switches designed and built in Britain by
British workers. Today, the Internet in Britain consists of a network of switches,
routers, and optical systems, largely designed in the U.S. but built in China,
Malaysia, Thailand, and Singapore. Increasingly, those network elements are not
just manufactured, but designed in China too.
Why does this matter, some will protest. If British industry
gives up on electronics, companies will surely be founded and jobs created in
other industries. Unfortunately, this
archaic piece of homespun economic wisdom (sometimes called the theory of
comparative advantage) does not apply to our 21st century world. As
Michael Spence has written: “many job opportunities in the United States are
shifting away from the sectors that are experiencing the most growth and to
those that are experiencing less.” (1) This blog relies partly on the analysis
of Professor Spence, who won the Nobel Prize for Economics in 2001. However I
am applying it in this article to Britain, because I think Britain is today
better placed than the U.S. to develop a post-globalization economic strategy.
Figure 2 shows the evolution of employment in three key
sectors in Britain since 1998. In the
last 18 years, the manufacturing sector has lost 30% of its employment, while
the health, social work, education and public administration sectors (let’s
call it HSWEPA) have gained 42% or 2.75 million jobs. The problem for the
economy is that manufacturing jobs are higher-paid than HSWEPA jobs, and
manufacturing pay tends to grow at faster rates. Figure 3 shows the recent
average weekly earnings of each sector. The differential between the two
sectors is about £160 a week. These are large numbers: in those 18
years, the British economy gained about 5 million new jobs, but more than half
of them were in the relatively low-paid, low-pay-growth HSWEPA sectors. It lost
1.3 million jobs in the higher-paid, high-growth manufacturing sector. It’s also
clear that the information & communication and finance & insurance
sectors grew rapidly (by 24%), but those 482,000 new jobs are simply not enough
to make a serious dent in the national trend towards lower-paid jobs.
Figure 2: Public sector jobs soar while manufacturing jobs decline |
Figure 3: UK1998-2015: an economy moving strongly to relatively low-wage employment |
Public commentators, including politicians, wave their flags
for many issues which are secondary to the main issue, which is I believe this
question of the industry and employment composition of the economy. Much has been written about productivity and
why Britain’s labor productivity growth has remained so low. It is a result of
this massive shift of labor from high-productivity-growth employment (mainly
manufacturing) to low-productivity-growth employment. And the shift
continues. Commentators also fret about
the slow recovery from the 2008 financial crisis. In spite of recovery,
manufacturing employment has been flat since 2008, an unprecedented phenomenon
in an economic recovery. Manufacturing continues to move to those nations that have
established themselves as leaders in the most important manufacturing sectors.
How can Britain enjoy a strong economic recovery when the most valuable and the
most pro-cyclical sector is in secular decline because it is packing its bags
and heading to Asia?
Industrial
Strategy
So what is to be done? First, three observations: first, to
express such views is not racist or isolationist. Unlike presidential candidate
Donald Trump, I am an internationalist. I believe the U.S. and the U.K. play
vital roles in maintaining world peace, and must continue to do so. But I
believe they can only continue to do so from a position of economic strength,
not weakness. Secondly, within a national economy, economic growth is more important
than redistribution. Redistribution is severely limited in an economy that is
only growing by 1% a year. Voters will rebel against tax increases. The social
services (a sore point with pro-Brexit voters) cannot be funded more aggressively
than they already are, because the national income pot is not growing fast
enough. On the other hand, more growth will make more redistribution possible. Thirdly,
growth cannot be achieved simply by investing in infrastructure or education.
These policies are valuable, but they will not by themselves produce the
profitable industries and high-paying jobs that are essential to succeeding in
a post-globalization world.
One glance at Figure 4 is sufficient to show that the
outstanding economic success story of the last 40 years has been Singapore.
Under Lee Kuan Yew’s leadership (1965-1990), Singapore rose to become the
number one nation in the world in per capita living standards, as measured by
the World Bank. This is a breathtaking achievement for a country so deprived of
natural resources it needs to import water. Korea is also climbing steadily up
the economic growth league table, from a position of abject poverty in the
1950s. With a population of 50 million, it recently surpassed Spain and Italy
in per capita living standards. The so-called Asian Tigers (Singapore, Korea,
Hong Kong, Taiwan) have recently been joined by China, and to a lesser extent
other Asian countries. All are pursuing variations of the strategy of
export-led growth that was invented after WWII by Japan. The most successful European economies, such
as Germany and Switzerland, have also pursued export-led growth strategies, not
so much as a conscious strategic decision as in Asia, but as a reaction to the
pressures of the competitive landscape they found in Europe when they first
began to industrialize.
Figure 4: Singapore and Hong Kong overtake USA in real living standards (Source: World Bank) |
Britain needs an industrial strategy that identifies and
then targets sectors where it can build worldwide leadership. This needs to be
a public-private partnership, but it must not involve the industries of the
past (coal, steel, etc.) as have all industrial policies for the last 100
years. It must identify sectors where Britain is small today but has the
potential to be a global player—based perhaps on mid-sized companies who have
established a unique technology or other advantage. It should involve private
businesspeople not from the world of the stock market but who have demonstrated
long-term vision and persistence—people like Richard Branson and James Dyson.
Their reputations should be hitched to the success of the strategy, because
today their reputations are more important to them than money. It should be
backed up with public investment funds to invest in technology and other potential
competitive differentiators, while enabling private companies to invest and
build a global position. The U.S. became the leader in designing the Internet,
and China in building the Internet, through multi-billion-dollar government
investment. Focus, persistence, and scale matter. Countries like Korea,
Switzerland, Sweden, Singapore have shown that from a relatively modest size,
one can build world-class positions. Through a form of the multiplier effect,
these industries then have an outsize impact on the entire national economy.
But policymakers should be clear on the goal: it is not
proliferating low-wage, “slave labor” jobs—voters told us on June 23rd
that is not what they want. Nor is it creating high-profit companies like Apple
that are incentivized to move the bulk of their jobs to Asia. The goal is to
create high-wage, high-productivity-growth jobs within Britain. In his article
on the U.S. situation, Professor Spence called for: “an agreement that restoring rewarding
employment opportunities for a full spectrum of Americans should be a
fundamental goal.” Companies should be incentivized, i.e. rewarded, for how
well they meet that goal.
They should also be disincentivized from undermining that
goal. Part of increasing national income and high-wage jobs is avoiding the
reduction of wages. An example: it was recently reported that IBM UK has a
confidential goal of moving 80% of its UK jobs to India. (IBM has neither
confirmed nor denied this report.) IBM’s logic is obvious—this will cut costs
and raise profitability at the struggling computer company. Not only are Indian
engineers less costly than British (or American) engineers; they are in general
highly qualified. However, this policy is inimical to Britain’s economic
growth. Incentives need to be put in place that favor companies employing
British engineers for British work. Some will protest that EU rules and WTO
rules forbid that. Well the EU is about to become history, and as for the WTO,
Singapore and Korea have practiced such policies for decades and they are
members in good standing of the WTO. Henry Higgins’ dictum on Edwardian society
applies well to international relations: it is not what you do that matters,
but how well you pronounce it.
As industrial strategy identifies industries where Britain
can achieve world leadership, controls and incentives need to be put in place
to enable those industries to grow on the British Isles, until they achieve the
necessary critical mass. I would not call this protectionism. I would call this
post-globalization economic policy. Singapore loudly supports
globalization—while ignoring the half-century of Singaporean economic policy
that favors domestic companies. Britain should do the same. To quote Professor
Spence once again: “Conditioning access to the domestic market on domestic
production is a form of protectionism and a way to limit the movement out of
the country of jobs and of value-added components in the supply chain. This is
more common than might be supposed.”
The reason why these policies have not been pursued in the
U.S. or the U.K. for the last 100 years is partly because so-called free trade was
successful in the last century, but also because both countries have large,
highly influential finance sectors that profit greatly from trade and
cross-border investment and acquisition activity. In the U.S., I believe the
situation is even worse. By pursuing an anti-employment strategy (i.e.
exporting jobs to Asia), the U.S. tech industry has cut itself off from its
most important source of support, its own employee base. The industry then had
no choice but to invest heavily in lobbying, since voters have little interest
in the goals of the tech industry. This is already backfiring, as voters turned
this year to Donald Trump and Bernie Sanders, because they saw that the
benefits of America’s much-vaunted technology revolution were accruing to a tiny
sliver of the population.
After a century of relative industrial decline, and 40 years
of absolute decline in key manufacturing sectors, the British people are ready
to embrace a new economic policy, to admit in effect that the policy of a
highly diversified economy governed by the short-term incentives of the stock
market is no longer suitable for a globalized world. Theresa May has already
indicated that she is open to some of these ideas. Some will say Britain cannot
do it, because free enterprise culture is too deeply embedded in the national
psyche. Yet a large and growing number
of Asian nations have made that transition. China’s culture was for six
centuries one of bureaucratic ossification and relative backwardness. Under
Deng, China shamelessly stole ideas from Japan and Singapore. On current
trends, it is set to become the world’s largest economy in ten years. Practical
realities have a way of making us change what once seemed immutable. The question
is how much more decline, how much more poverty, do we have to endure before we
acknowledge that the solution was there all the time, staring us in the face
from its perch on the shores of the Pacific?
Notes
(1) Spence, Michael, Globalization
and Unemployment, The Downside of Integrating Markets, Foreign Affairs,
July/August 2011.
No comments:
Post a Comment